Freedom Discussions

The Costs of Government

by Robert P. Murphy, LEL

Critics of government intervention have pointed out the waste of resources associated with various programs and regulations. Yet, even most fans of the free market would be surprised to see how much richer the average American would be if the government restricted its activities to protecting citizens from domestic criminals and foreign armies. In this article, I sketch out some of government’s big-ticket wealth-destroying activities to come up with a rough estimate of how much poorer Big Government makes the average citizen. The bottom line is that getting rid of justthese activities would increase the average American’s real income by 18 percent in a very short period.
Methodology

One method for generating a ballpark estimate is to calculate the fraction of the economy absorbed by government at all levels. In the 4th quarter of 2009, federal, state, and local government spending accounted for 35 percent of U.S. GDP.1 Now, suppose that an extreme critic of the government thought that, on net, it provides no services—meaning that whatever good things the government does (locking up murderers, teaching most kids to read, etc.) is counterbalanced by the bad things it does (locking up speculators who promote market efficiency, teaching most kids that the New Deal ended the Great Depression, etc). If that critic is right, then getting rid of the government altogether would return that 35 percent of GDP to the taxpayers, immediately increasing the real income of the average American by about 54 percent.2

However, trying to calculate the waste of government by analyzing total expenditures is a poor method. A large fraction of government spending consists of transfers, which do not destroy the actual resources being redistributed. For example, retired individuals may have railed against “Big Government” during their peak earning years, but now many of them would lose out if Social Security and Medicare spending were cut, even if the rollback went hand-in-hand with massive tax cuts. Similarly, many poor residents in urban neighborhoods might not gain from the “services” of local vice squads and the CIA, but they might gain from free (to them) public schooling for their children and income-assistance programs.

Because transfer payments create obvious winners and losers, this article does not examine overall government budgets. Rather, it looks at specific government functions and comes up with quick estimates for how much money is wasted, relative to the private sector providing the same services. We also consider some of the major categories of “deadweight loss” associated with government policies.

Consumption and Investment Spending at Various Government Levels

To avoid the problem of simple transfers, we can focus on government purchases of goods and services. But because government typically has higher expenses to produce an equivalent output, we can’t treat government purchases as equivalent to, say, a private corporation’s investment spending.

To provide some empirical mooring, we can look at input versus output in K-12 schooling. Andrew Coulson recently estimated that the Washington, D.C. public schools spend an average of $24,606 per pupil annually. In contrast, D.C.’s private schools—which include some of the most elite institutions in the country—spend only $14,534.3

Despite their lower funding, private-school students consistently outperform their public-school peers. However, much of the disparity disappears once differences in student background are taken into account.4 Assume for the sake of argument that public and private schools do a comparable job educating equivalent students.

Superficially, these results suggest that even for a local task, subject to immediate feedback from voters (and parents), the government consumes almost 70 percent more resources to produce the same output as the private sector. Yet, because Coulson’s figures include some federal funds and because the effect we are measuring might be exaggerated near D.C., let us conservatively say that for standard services that could be handled just as well by the private sector, local governments spend 50 percent more than the private sector to do an equivalent job.

We have reason to believe that this estimate should be much higher for state and, especially, federal activities. For one thing, Charles Tiebout suggests that as political jurisdictions grow larger, the political class becomes less responsive to the voters and caters more to special interests.5 Surely a compilation of wasteful federal uses of tax dollars would dwarf a compilation of state or local abuses.

Besides weaker accountability to the voters, higher levels of government tend to waste more resources per dollar of expenditure because of the mix of programs offered by the federal versus state and local levels. When local officials waste money, they might, say, subsidize a convention center or sports stadium and use downtown real estate in a suboptimal way. But when federal officials waste money, they might spend millions on antitrust prosecutions of large firms that have kept prices low and, thus, made competition too intense for their competitors. There is no analog in such cases for private provision because it’s not a “service” at all.6 It’s true that local governments provide dubious “services” just as federal politicians do, but we assume they constitute a smaller proportion of local activities, leading us to choose a lower estimate of the overall waste per dollar of purchases.

With these considerations in mind, let’s assume that local governments use 50 percent more resources than necessary to fund their legitimate services, that state governments use 75 percent more, and that the federal government spends twice as much (100 percent) on its legitimate services, compared to a private counterpart. What this implies, using simple algebra, is that 33 percent of local government payroll, 43 percent of state government payroll, and fully 50 percent of federal civilian payroll is wasteful.

According to the Bureau of Economic Analysis, annualized federal nondefense purchases were $377 billion in the 4th quarter of 2009. State and local governments spent $1,786 billion purchasing goods and services during 2009.7 If we apply the 50- percent discount to the federal figure, and a (weighted) 35-percent figure to the state and local expenditures, we come up with an estimated ($377bn × 50% + $1786bn × 35%) = $813 billion in wasted resources.

Subsidized Schooling

Beyond the explicit expenditures, government involvement in schooling has another large cost: By keeping millions of students cooped up in classrooms who would otherwise be working for pay, mandatory attendance laws and subsidies for post-secondary schooling suppress economic activity.

Of course, there is a potential tradeoff in which attendance laws and student aid reduce potential output from young workers as they stay longer in school, but lead to higher output after they have graduated with better skills. However, it is not obvious that the massive government support for schooling actually yields a more-educatedpopulation, particularly as the education pertains to on-the-job skills. Indeed, a leading economic model interprets college and advanced degrees as signals to the employer of the aptitude of a particular student.8 Many businesses will pay a high starting salary to a 4.0 history major from Harvard, not because they need someone with a thorough knowledge of medieval Europe, but because the type of student who achieves this will probably succeed in many job environments.

To the extent that this “signaling game” characterizes formal education, schooling is like an arms race between students. If they could collectively agree to spend less time in school—with far fewer people going on to grad school and with fewer people taking it for granted that “everybody should go to college”—then employers’ expectations would adjust. Students, on average, wouldn’t be hurt in their career prospects and would gain by having the option to start their careers earlier.

Things would be better for the students who remained in school, too. As a former college professor, I would have much preferred preparing to teach, say, the top half of my students in each class, to having to cater to the ones who always asked, “Will this be on the exam?”9

Let us arbitrarily assume that without government encouragement, enrollment in college and graduate programs would fall by half, and that this shift would yield a citizenry (on average) just as educated. With these assumptions, the increase in output from half of the current enrolled students entering the workforce would be a pure gain.

In 1999, there were 12.6 million Americans enrolled in undergraduate degree-granting institutions. If we assume that half of these young people would get jobs earning $20,000 on average, were it not for government support, we can add another $126 billion to our tally. If we assume that half of the 1.8 million enrolled in graduate programs could get jobs earning $35,000 on average, we can add another $32 billion.10

Military Spending

One of the biggest components of federal spending is the military budget. Including supplemental funding for the operations in Iraq and Afghanistan, total military spending for Fiscal Year 2010 will probably be some $720 billion.11

It is difficult to evaluate this aspect of government activity because there is no obvious private-sector analog to the operations of the Department of Defense. However, consider this: Despite the hundreds of billions spent over the years to influence foreign events and establish a worldwide intelligence network, 19 men with boxcutters were somehow able to bring down the World Trade Center and attack the Pentagon on September 11, 2001.

For the sake of argument, let’s suppose that a “Fortress America” defense, in which the United States did not try to police the world but, instead, concentrated a smaller force at home to deter explicit attacks, could provide the same general level of security. And we’ll arbitrarily pick $150 billion as the annual expense of maintaining this deterrent. Note that even by spending this smaller amount, the U.S. would still lead the world in military spending, and many of the other contenders are explicit U.S. allies. With the U.S. already starting with its stockpile of advanced weaponry and trained forces, and still spending more than any other country in the world on its military, it is difficult to see what power would cross the oceans and credibly threaten an invasion, especially considering how many private citizens would rush to join militias and the National Guard in the months before such a large-scale attack.12

If, indeed, a “Fortress America” strategy costing $150 billion annually could provide American citizens with comparable protection from foreign attack, this means that the military currently uses some $570 billion per year that could be returned to the private sector.

Read the rest at this link.

Hat Tip: Gadget42

Share